If you have not read Paul Collier’s Wars,Guns, and Votes, I encourage you to read it. It complements his
previous book TheBottom Billion by expanding on the aspect of democracy as it
relates, in large part, to those bottom billion countries and to those
countries coming out of conflict situations. We have good examples to watch
today: Egypt, Libya, Afghanistan, Iraq, maybe Syria in the not too distant
future. While I have issues with the universality of Collier’s arguments, as
they apply to countries not necessarily in the bottom billion, I tend to favor
his analysis that new democracy influences new violence.
One
of the summary theses Paul Collier suggests is that, "Democracy…does not
seem to enhance the prospects of internal peace." In fact, Collier
suggests that the contrary is more so the case with the introduction of
democracy, that states are more likely to experience conflict, initially,
rather than experience peace. At first glance, his notion seems to fly in the
face of the pursuit of democracy and the good that democracy should represent.
However, from a purely technical analysis, Collier's point bears truth in many
cases. In fact, the United States suffered a rather long period of internal
fiscal, political, and social conflict lasting several decades even producing a
civil war. Arguably, some of those political and social conflicts have even
extended well into the 20th century.
Empirical findings and theoretical arguments
One
of the more illustrative consistencies Collier finds is that elections capture
the potential failure of low-income state democracy. Elections are one of the
defining characteristics of democracies, so to hold elections should indicate
the process of democracy is working. Unfortunately, Collier believes this to be
foolishly untrue. He deems the late 20th century democratic wave as superficial
and instead a, "spread of elections." His data suggest the result has
been a lack of legitimate elections that validate new societies. This false
democracy is what he calls, "Democrazy." In other words, it is well
short of a functioning democracy.
For example, Collier found
consistency in the rate of political violence. Statistical analysis of several
factors from assassinations to "full-blooded civil war" all
demonstrated the same thing among bottom billion countries. Their pattern
showed that, "democracy increased political violence." Anecdotally
what he infers is that under dictatorial regimes, the opportunity of dissident
and disgruntled groups to react against the government was suppressed. Collier
places himself in the shoes of a dictator and wonders what he would do to
suppress political violence. The answer is obvious - stop it because the
dictator can. However, in a democracy, the government theoretically cannot just
stop outward anti-government sentiment without potentially acting counter to
democratic, free ideals.
He uses Iraq as a case-in-point, and
this author concurs with the example. Prior to democratizing, Iraq was under
the thumb of Saddam Hussein. Albeit a suppressive and repressive regime, Saddam
controlled outward public sentiment. When Saddam ceased to exist, so too did
that strong governmental control. The result has been a backlash of democratic
political fervor that to this day is not fully controlled.
Another empirical example considers
the choice of nominees in bottom billion democracies. Collier identifies that
those countries tend to attract corrupt and often criminal nominees for
elections. The unfortunate result is that even if an election were fairly held,
the resultant choices would all be bad anyway. Therefore, the free election
system is somewhat doomed to fail. This attraction is the result of a
corruption incentive. Collier suggests that corruption draws more dishonest
candidates than honest ones. Consequently, one of the consistencies among the
bottom billion countries is debilitating corruption.
Additionally ethnic divisions
increase the likelihood of political violence. Collier found a correlation
between the high-income societies being more capable of handling diverse
societies. He illustrates the United States and countries throughout Europe as
models. Unfortunately, those low-income countries that are also ethnically
diverse are prone to political violence. He finds that, "Fundamentally,
the results so far suggest that ethnic diversity makes social cooperation more
difficult" which is exacerbated by lower incomes. He suggests the natural
reaction to offset political violence between ethnic groups is to resort to an
autocracy or even dictatorial regimes because only then can one power enforce
security.
The underlying theoretical argument
in the many empirical examples he puts forward is that ultimately the act of
electing candidates does little to nothing to promoting democratic growth and
that it actually inhibits good democracy. As states in the bottom billion deal
with problematic elections resulting in illegitimate governments, they
perpetuate the state's inability to manage public goods. The primary public
goods include accountability and security. His solution is for the
international community to step in to manage the resourcing of those public
goods until the state is capable of managing them alone. He offers three
proposals for international action to deal with providing the public goods of
accountability and security.
Proposal 1: Harnessing violence for democracy
His
first proposal attempts to legitimize the process of free and fair elections.
Because so much turmoil comes from the illegitimate elections, it is therefore
incumbent upon the international community to enforce a standard of elections.
It is also theoretically incumbent upon the bottom billion states to adhere to
the international standards of election accountability. What he does not
suggest is that the international community enforce a standard of democracy per
se. Instead, it is the process of getting to democracy that needs to be upheld
- the legitimate elections themselves. This involves a potentially seven-step
process of promoting standards and submitting to them voluntarily.
Proposal
1 aims to provide the first public good of accountability. Doing so lends
credibility to a freely elected government, and in theory effects trust amongst
the population that their interests are fairly represented. It also attempts to
bill the government as an honest broker of itself because the idea behind
proposal one is that voluntarily, states would submit to international scrutiny
and assistance establishing credible elections. This means then, that countries
facing political upheaval, albeit legitimate, must therefore surrender to the
will of the people to validate the trust relationship between state and people.
Collier notes that, "Proposal 1 [sic] provides some rules for how a
government acquires power."
Proposal 2: Enforcing probity in public spending
His
second proposal attempts to legitimize the use of public money. Collier's
analyses suggest that corruption plays a large part in fomenting political
violence among the bottom billion. The international community needs to
"provide some rules for the use of power" so that public resources
(money) do not get misused. This is particularly important because Collier
correctly points out that states in the bottom billion have a GDP comprised
largely of aid dollars. Afghanistan is the shining example right now. Currently
Afghanistan's licit GDP comes from aid dollars. Not only does Afghanistan have
a responsibility to its people to use that money wisely; it has a
responsibility to use that borrowed money wisely because of the lenders.
Therefore,
the international community certainly has an interest in enforcing proper
fiscal accountability. To do this Collier suggests that two things are needed,
"capacity and verification." The states need the capacity to separate
their funding from policy. More importantly, though, heavy scrutiny must be
placed on the flow of money that supports policies. He refers to public money
"leaking" from holes and that accounting efforts should apply a
"forensic approach" to identifying and patching those holes. Again,
he does not suggest that the international community should direct states how
to run their state - in other words, which policies to adopt. Rather, the
probity ensures that public revenue does not "leak" through holes in
the policies. This too legitimizes the public good of accountability.
Proposal 3: The international supply of security
His
third proposal addresses the public good of security. The problem with states
in the bottom billion is that even if they wanted to abide by non-corrupt and
legitimate election practices, their capacity to protect the governing
institution is limited. They simply cannot secure themselves. Therefore, the
international community must provide some measure of security especially in
post-conflict settings. It is in this proposal that Collier confuses his
realist assertion that R2P is an affront to sovereignty while the international
community has an interest in enforcing security upon states in the bottom
billion.
He
is not quite clear, however, how that will effectively happen. One option he
suggests is through a proxy tax by donor nations. He offers that donor nations
should link aid dollars to military spending programs because many times needy
states use aid dollars to fund military programs. While this understandably
makes sense, what does not make sense is his assertion that those troubled
states should somehow curb military spending. He says, "Given that
military spending is at least in part a regional public bad, it should be
discouraged." The proxy tax is a method to discourage military spending.
Yet, how would a state reinforce its capacity for security without bolstering
military spending? His proposal creates a confusing paradox that may do more to
promote illegitimate resourcing of security forces rather than engaging in a
legitimate strategy to develop security.
Relationship between democracy and political violence
I
concur with Collier's empirical and theoretical notion that a relationship
between democracy and political violence does exist. Having witnessed it first
hand in a few countries, induced democracy does create a vacuum in public
expression. The vacuum is not so much that violent public expression does not
exist. Rather, it does exist, and whereas a previous regime contained that
expression, newfound freedom without boundaries cannot contain bundled
sentiment. Similar to a balloon in a vacuum chamber, as pressure is removed
(effect of democracy), the balloon grows (outward public expression). I believe
that countries that have experienced extreme control, do not know how to express
sentiments when the lid of control is removed.
This comment has been removed by the author.
ReplyDeleteI surprise how much effort you put to create such a great informative website
ReplyDelete223 Brass Bulk with Free Shipping
I think this is an informative post and it is very beneficial and knowledgeable. Therefore, I would like to thank you for the endeavors that you have made in writing this article. All the content is absolutely well-researched. Thanks... buy cheap guns online
ReplyDeleteUsually, the bigger the binoculars, the more power they have, though this is not always true. Some higher end binoculars are smaller, but give you much more magnification for their size than even great big ones. binoculars
ReplyDeleteTelangana Board of Secondary Education will release TS 10th Model Paper 2022. The board publishes SSC sample papers in pdf format for the subjects of Social Science, Mathematics, Science, Hindi, and English. Candidates can use the pdf links to get previous year's Telangana State 10th class sample paper for practise and to Telangana 10th Model Paper 2022 familiarise themselves with the test question paper. They should have studied the syllabus thoroughly before attempting to tackle the old question paper. To learn more about TS 10th 2022 Model Paper, read the entire article.
ReplyDelete